OPTIMUM PORTFOLIO SELECTION
PORTFOLIO
SELECTION
The objective of
every investor is to maximize his returns and minimize his risk.
Diversification is the method adopted to reduce the risk. It essentially
results in the construction of portfolios. The proper goal of construction of portfolios
would be to generate a portfolio that provides the highest return and lowest
risk. Such a portfolio would be an optimal portfolio. The process of finding
the optimal portfolio is described as portfolio selection.
The conceptual
framework and analytical tools for determining the optimal portfolio in
disciplined and objective manner have been provided by Harry Markowitz in his
pioneering work on portfolio analysis described in his 1952 “JOURNAL
OF FINANCE” article and subsequent book in 1959. His method of
portfolio selection is come to be known as Markowitz model. In fact,
Markowitz work marked the beginning of what is today the Modern Portfolio
Theory.
FEASIBLE
SET OF PORTFOLIOS
With limited number of securities an investor can create a very large
number of portfolios by combining these securities in different proportions.
These constitute the feasible set of portfolios in which the investor can
possibly invest. This is also known as the portfolio opportunity set.
Each portfolio in
the opportunity set is characterized by an expected return and a measure of
risk, viz., and variance of the returns. Not every portfolio in the portfolio
opportunity set is of interest to an investor. In an opportunity set some
portfolios will be dominant over the others. A portfolio will dominate the
other if it has either a lower variance and the same expected return as the
other, or a higher return and the same variance as the other. Portfolios that are dominated by the others
are called as insufficient portfolios. An investor would not be
interested in all the portfolios in the opportunity set. He would be interested
only in the efficient portfolios.
EFFICIENT
SET OF PORTFOLIOS
To understand the
concept of efficient portfolios, let us consider various combinations of
securities and designate them as portfolios 1 to n. the expected returns of
these portfolios may be worked out. The risk of these portfolios may be
estimated by measuring the variance of the portfolio returns. The table below
shows illustrative returns and variance of some portfolios:
Portfolio No.
|
Expected Return
(per cent)
|
Variance
(risk)
|
1
|
5.6
|
4.5
|
2
|
7.8
|
5.8
|
3
|
9.2
|
7.6
|
4
|
10.5
|
8.1
|
5
|
11.7
|
8.1
|
6
|
12.4
|
9.3
|
7
|
13.5
|
9.5
|
8
|
13.5
|
11.3
|
9
|
15.7
|
12.7
|
10
|
16.8
|
12.9
|
If we compare portfolios 4 and 5, for the same variance of 8.1
portfolio no. 5 gives a higher expected return of 11.7, making it more
efficient than portfolio no. 4. Again, if we compare portfolios 7 and 8 for the
same expected return of 13.5%, the variance is lower for portfolio no.7, making
it more efficient than portfolio no. 8. Thus the selection of the portfolios by
the investor will be guided by two criteria:
- Given two portfolios with the same expected return, the investor will prefer the one with the lower risk.
- Given two portfolios with the same risk, the investor will prefer the one with the higher expected returns.
These criteria are based on the assumption that investors are
rational and also risk averse. As they are rational they would prefer more
returns to less returns. As they are risk averse, they would prefer less risk
to more risk.
The concept of
efficient sets can be illustrated with the help of a graph. The expected
returns and the variance can be depicted on a XY graph, measuring the expected
returns on the Y-axis and the variance on the X-axis. The figure below depicts
such a graph.
As a single point in the risk-return space would represent each
possible portfolio in the opportunity set or the feasible set of portfolio
enclosed within the two axes of the graph. The shaded area in the graph
represents the set of all possible portfolios that can be constructed from a
given set of securities. This opportunity set of portfolios takes a concave
shape because it consists of portfolios containing securities that are less
than perfectly correlated with each other.
|
Let us closely examine the diagram above. Consider portfolios F and
E. Both the portfolios have the same expected return but portfolio E has less
risk. Hence portfolio E would
be preferred to portfolio F. Now consider portfolios C and E. Both have the same risk,
but portfolio E offers
more return for the same risk. Hence portfolio E would be preferred to portfolio C. Thus for any point
in the risk-return space, an investor would like to move as far as possible in
the direction of increasing returns and also as far as possible in the
direction of decreasing risk. Effectively, he would be moving towards the left
in search of decreasing risk and upwards in search of increasing returns.
Let us consider portfolios C and A. Portfolio C would be preferred
to portfolio A because it offers less risk for the same level of return. In the
opportunity set of portfolios represented in the diagram, portfolio C has the
lowest risk compared to all other portfolios. Here portfolio C in this diagram
represents the Global Minimum Variance Portfolio.
Comparing portfolios A and B,
we find that portfolio B
is preferable to portfolio A because it offers higher return for the
same level of risk. In this diagram, point B represents the portfolio with the
highest expected return among all the portfolios in the feasible set.
Thus we
find that portfolios lying in the North West boundary of the shaded area are
more efficient than all the portfolios in the interior of the shaded area. This
boundary of the shaded area is called the Efficient Frontier because it
contains all the efficient portfolios in the opportunity set. The set of
portfolios lying between the global minimum variance portfolio and the maximum
return portfolio on the efficient frontier represents the efficient set of
portfolios. The efficient frontier is shown separately in Fig.
The efficient frontier is a concave curve in the risk-return space
that extends from the minimum variance portfolio to the maximum return
portfolio.
SELECTION OF OPTIMAL
PORTFOLIO
The portfolio selection problem is really the process of delineating
the efficient portfolios and then selecting the best portfolio from the set.
Rational investors will obviously prefer to invest in the efficient
portfolios. The particular portfolio that an individual investor will select
from the efficient frontier will depend on that investor's degree of aversion
to risk. A highly risk averse investor will hold a portfolio on the lower left
hand segment of the efficient frontier, while an investor who is not too risk
averse will hold one on the upper portion of the efficient frontier.
The selection of the optimal portfolio thus depends on the
investor's risk aversion, or conversely on his risk tolerance. This can be
graphically represented through a series of risk return utility curves or
indifference curves. The indifference curves of an investor are shown in Fig.
Each curve represents different combinations of risk and return all of which
are equally satisfactory to the concerned investor. The investor is indifferent
between the successive points in the curve. Each successive curve moving
upwards to the left represents a higher level of satisfaction or utility. The
investor's goal would be to maximize his utility by moving up to the higher
utility curve. The optimal portfolio for an investor would be the one at the
point of tangency between the efficient frontier and his risk-return utility or
indifference curve.
This is shown in Fig. The point O'
represents the optimal portfolio. Markowitz used the technique of quadratic
programming to identify the efficient portfolios. Using the expected return and
risk of each security under consideration and the covariance estimates for each
pair of securities, he calculated risk and return for all possible portfolios.
Then, for any specific value of expected portfolio return, he determined the
least risk portfolio using quadratic programming. With another value of
expected portfolio return, a similar procedure again gives the minimum risk portfolio.
The process is repeated with different values of expected return, the resulting
minimum risk portfolios constitute the set of efficient portfolio
Comments
Post a Comment