CAPM & APT
CAPM
Capital asset pricing means
defining an appropriate risk-adjusted rate of return for a given asset. Capital
Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) is a model that helps in this exercise.
William Sharpe, Treynor and
Lintner contributed to the development of this model. An important consequence
of the modern portfolio theory as introduced by Markowitz was that the only
meaningful aspect of total risk to consider for any individual asset is its
contribution to the total risk of a portfolio. CAPM extended Harry Markowitz’s
portfolio theory to introduce the notions of systematic and unsystematic (or
unique) risk.
With the introduction of
risk-free lending and borrowing, the efficient frontier of Markowitz was
expanded and it was shown that only one risky portfolio (the tangency
portfolio) mattered in evaluating the portfolio risk contribution
characteristics of any asset. CAPM demonstrated that the tangency portfolio was nothing but
the market portfolio consisting of all risky assets in proportion to
their market capitalisation.
Since the market
portfolio includes all the risky assets in their relative proportions, it is a
fully diversified portfolio. The inherent risk of each asset that can be
eliminated by belonging to the portfolio has already been eliminated. Only the
market risk (also called systematic risk) will remain. This has been discussed
in detail in the last unit.
The CAPM is a
model for risky asset pricing. Using a statistical technique called linear
regression, the total risk of each risky asset is separated into two
components:
variability in its returns (i.e., risk) that is related with the variability of
returns in the market portfolio (its contribution to systematic risk)
variability in
its returns that is unrelated with the variability of returns in the market
portfolio (called unsystematic risk).
Systematic and
Unsystematic Risk
Every
investment portfolio has a risk element, which is the investor will always not
be certain whether the investment will be able to generate income as per
investor’s requirement. The degree of risk defers from industry to industry but
also from company to company. It is not possible to eliminate the investment
risk altogether but with careful diversification the risk might be minimised.
Provided that the investor diversify their investments in a suitably wide
portfolio, the investments which perform well and those which perform badly,
should tend to cancel each other out, and much risk is diversified away.
Risks that can be reduced through diversification are referred to as unsystematic risk as they are associated with a particular company or sector of the business. Remember investors are supposed to be compensated for any risk assumed, but with unsystematic risk the investor will not be have any extra risk premium as it can be eliminated through diversification.
Risks that can be reduced through diversification are referred to as unsystematic risk as they are associated with a particular company or sector of the business. Remember investors are supposed to be compensated for any risk assumed, but with unsystematic risk the investor will not be have any extra risk premium as it can be eliminated through diversification.
Some investments are by their nature more risky than others. These risks are called as systematic risk which will always remain in an investment despite holding a well diversified investment opportunities. If an investor would not take systematic risk, then should be prepared to settle for risk free return which has a lower level of return. Where an investor assumes the systematic risk, and then should expect to earn a return which is higher than a risk free rate of return. The amount of systematic risk in an investment varies between different types of investment. The systematic risk in the operating cash flows of a tourism company which is highly sensitive to consumer’s spending power might be greater than the systematic risk for a company which operates a chain of supermarkets. Systematic risk of a risky asset exists in the market portfolio and cannot be eliminated by portfolio diversification. Investors who want to hold the market portfolio must be and are rewarded. Unsystematic risk for any risky asset cannot be eliminated by holding the market portfolio (which includes the risky asset in question).
Thus
the major conclusion of CAPM is that expected return on an asset is related to
its systematic and not to its total risk or standard deviation. Its systematic
risk is given by its beta coefficient (β). An asset’s beta is a measure of its
co-movement with the market index.
Assumptions of CAPM
All investors are
assumed to follow the mean-variance approach, i.e. the risk-averse investor
will ascribe to the methodology of reducing portfolio risk by combining assets
with counterbalancing correlations.
Assets are
infinitely divisible.
There is a
risk-free rate at which an investor may lend or borrow. This risk-free rate is
the same for all investors.
Taxes and
transactions costs are irrelevant.
All investors have
same holding period.
Information is
freely and instantly available to all investors.
Investors have
homogeneous expectations i.e. all investors have the same expectations with
respect to the inputs that are used to derive the Markowitz efficient
portfolios (asset returns, variances and correlations).
Markets are assumed to be
perfectly competitive i.e. the number of buyers and sellers is sufficiently
large, and all investors are small enough relative to the market, so that no
individual investor can influence an asset’s price.
Consequently all investors are
price takers. Market price is determined by matching supply and demand.
Investors are considered to be a
homogeneous group. They have the same expectations, same one-period horizon,
same risk-free rate and information is freely and instantly available to all
investors. This is an extreme case, but it allows the focus to change from how
an individual should invest to what would happen to security prices if everyone
invested in a similar manner.
Some
of these assumptions of CAPM are clearly unrealistic. But relaxing many of
these assumptions would have only minor influence on the model and would not
change its main implications or conclusions. The primary way to judge a theory
is to see how well it explains and helps predict behaviour. While CAPM does not
completely explain the variation in stock returns, it remains the most widely
used method for calculating the cost of capital.
Market Portfolio
If investors have the same
expectations, same one-period horizon, same risk-free rate and if information
is freely and instantly available to all investors, it can be shown that the
portfolio of risky assets lying on the efficient frontier that the investors
hold (the tangency portfolio) is the same for everyone. It is the market
portfolio.
Market portfolio consists of all
assets available to investors, and each asset is held in proportion to its
market value relative to the total market value of all assets.
The tangency portfolio should be
the market portfolio. Reason being the tangency portfolio is a portfolio that
every rational investor would hold. If a risky asset was not included in this
portfolio there would be no demand for it and it would not exist.
As
far as the proportion of each risky asset in this market portfolio is
concerned, market efficiency and equilibrium ensure that the demand for each
asset is reflected in its price so that the relative market capitalisation of
each asset (as a percentage of the entire market for risky assets) would be the
weight or proportion of each asset in the market portfolio.
The Beta Factor and Risk
Free Rate of Return
A share’s beta factor is the measures of
measure of its volatility in terms of market risk. The beta factor of the
market as a whole is 1.0. Market risk makes market returns volatile and the
beta factor is simply a yardstick against which the risk of other investments
can be measured. Risk or uncertainty describes a situation where there is not
first one possible outcome but array of potential returns. Risk is measured as
the beta factor or B.
·
Negative beta -
A beta less than 0 - which would indicate an inverse relation to the market -
is possible but highly unlikely. Some investors used to believe that gold and
gold stocks should have negative betas because they tended to do better when
the stock market declined, but this hasn't proved to be true over the long
term.
·
Beta of 0 -
Basically, cash has a beta of 0. In other words, regardless of which way the
market moves, the value of cash remains unchanged (given no inflation).
·
Beta between 0
and 1 - Companies with volatilities lower than the market have
a beta of less than 1 (but more than 0). As we mentioned earlier, many
utilities fall in this range.
·
Beta of 1 -
A beta of 1 represents the volatility of the given index
used to represent the overall market, against which other stocks and their
betas are measured. is such an index. If a stock has a beta of one, it will
move the same amount and direction as the index. So, an index fund that mirrors
the S&P 500 will have a beta close to 1.
·
Beta greater than 1 -
This denotes a volatility that is greater than the broad-based index. Again, as
we mentioned above, many technology companies on the Sensexhave a beta higher
than 1.
·
Beta greater than
100 -
This is impossible as it essentially denotes a volatility that is 100 times
greater than the market. If a stock had a beta of 100, it would be expected to
go to 0 on any decline in the stock market. If you ever see a beta of over 100
on a research site it is usually the result of a statistical error, or the
given stock has experienced large swings due to low liquidity,
such as an over-the-counter stock.
For the most part, stocks of well-known companies rarely ever have a beta
higher than 4.
·
- The market as a whole has B = 1
- Risk free security has a B = 0
- A security with a B < 1 is lesser risky than average Market
- A security with a B > 1 has risk above market
- Risk free security has a B = 0
- A security with a B < 1 is lesser risky than average Market
- A security with a B > 1 has risk above market
Essentially, beta expresses the
fundamental tradeoff between minimizing risk and maximizing return. Let's
give an illustration. Say a company has a beta of 2. This means it is
two times as volatile as the overall market. Let's say we expect the market to
provide a return of 10% on an investment. We would expect the company to return
20%. On the other hand, if the market were to decline and provide a return
of -6%, investors in that company could expect a return of -12% (a loss of
12%). If a stock had a beta of 0.5, we would expect it to be half as volatile
as the market: a market return of 10% would mean a 5% gain for the company.)
The Capital Market Line (CML)
The
CML says that the expected return on a portfolio is equal to the risk-free rate
plus a risk premium.
Where, rf = risk-free rate, rm =
return on market portfolio, σm = standard deviation of the return on market
portfolio, σp = standard deviation of the return on the portfolio. Graphically, the
CML can be drawn as below:
EF is the efficient frontier, M
is the market portfolio and the line tangent to the efficient frontier and
joining the risk-free rate (rf) with the market portfolio (M) and going beyond
is the Capital Market Line (CML).
The risk-free rate compensates
investors for the time value of money while the risk premium compensates
investors for bearing risk. The risk premium is equal to the market price of
risk times the quantity of risk for the portfolio (as measured by the standard
deviation of the portfolio).
The term (rm – rf) is the
expected return of the market beyond the risk-free return. It is a measure of
the reward for holding the risky market portfolio rather than the risk-free
asset. The term m is the risk of the market portfolio. Thus, the slope of the
CML measures the reward per unit of market risk. It determines the additional
return needed to compensate for a unit change in risk. It is also called the
market price of risk.
Capital Market Line (CML) leads
all investors to invest in the tangency portfolio (M portfolio) which is the investment
decision. Individual investors differ in position on the CML depending on risk preferences
(which leads to the financing decision). Risk-averse investors will lend
part of the portfolio at the risk-free rate (rf) and invest the remainder in
the market portfolio (points left of M). Aggressive investors would borrow
funds at the risk-free rate and invest everything in the market portfolio
(points to the right of M)
The Security Market Line (SML)
For an individual risky asset,
the relevant risk measure is the covariance of its returns with the return on
the market portfolio. An extension of covariance called beta coefficient of an
asset, βi is defined as:
Where σ i,M = covariance of the
return on the asset and the return on the market portfolio.
σ2M = variance of return on the
market portfolio.
The CAPM equation, whose
graphical representation is the Security Market Line (SML), describes a linear
relationship between risk and return for an individual asset. Risk, in this
case, is measured by beta (β). Required rate of return for a particular asset
in a market depends on its sensitivity to the movement of the market portfolio
(i.e. the broader market). This sensitivity is known as the asset beta (β) and
reflects systematic risk of the asset. For the market portfolio, beta of the
portfolio, βM = 1 by definition. More sensitive assets have a higher beta while
less sensitive assets have lower beta. Expected return on any security or
portfolio is equal to the risk-free rate plus a risk premium.
Thus expected return on a
security (ri) depends on the risk-free rate, (rf,) which is the
pure time value of money, (rM – rf,) the reward for bearing systematic
risk and βi, the amount of unsystematic risk.
CML and SML
The Security Market Line (SML)
and the Capital Market Line (CML) are sometimes confused with each other. CML
is a straight line on a plot of absolute returns versus risk that begins at the
point of the risk-free asset and extends to its point of tangency with the
efficient frontier for risky assets that we call the market portfolio and
beyond. Along CML, there are only differing proportions of investing in the
market portfolio and borrowing or lending at the risk-free rate to either
increase or decrease the exposure to the market portfolio.
SML allows us to represent the
risk and return characteristics of every asset in the market portfolio. Instead
of dealing with the market portfolio as a whole or as a single entity, SML
disaggregates the market portfolio into its individual risky assets and plots
return against the only meaningful (or rewarded) aspect of total risk for each
asset that is rewarded (its beta).
Thus CML shows the relation
between the expected return from a portfolio and its standard deviation and
helps investors in their capital allocation problem, while SML shows the
relation between expected return and beta and helps investors in security
selection and individual asset pricing.
Limitations of Capital Asset
Pricing Model
CAPM is a single
period model.
It is a single factor
linear model. It defines risky asset returns solely as a function of the
asset’s contribution to the systematic risk of the market portfolio.
The true market
portfolio defined by the theory behind the CAPM is unobservable. Therefore, one
has to select and use a market portfolio such as Nifty or Sensex as “proxy.”
If we use historical data to
estimate the inputs for the basic CAPM (risk-free rate, beta and market risk
premium), we are making the assumption that the past (specifically the period
that we select for the historical data) is the best predictor of the future.
Over the years, a lot of research
has been done to test the validity of CAPM but there are problems encountered
in doing this research. CAPM is a theory about expected returns whereas
we can only measure actual returns. This makes it difficult to test the
theory as it is conceived. Another problem in testing CAPM is that the market
portfolio should include all assets, not just stocks traded in stock exchanges.
In practice, most of the tests use stock market indexes such as the S & P
500 as proxies for the market portfolio.
The results of the research, in
general, indicate that the model fails a rigorous test of validity. The results
do generally indicate that any asset’s returns are, as CAPM asserts, a linear
function of its non-diversifiable risk. But these studies, strictly interpreted
find a different intercept and a different slope for SML than the one predicted
by CAPM—SML seems flatter than that predicted by CAPM.
In spite of its
limitations, most observers regard CAPM as the best tool to describe how assets
are priced in efficient markets at equilibrium. The model has found its way
into the practical tool kit of many security analysts, portfolio designers,
financial managers, investors etc. Corporations often use CAPM to help estimate
the cost of equity financing, which is in turn an important component of the
weighted average cost of capital (WACC).
Single Factor Model and Variance
The simplest factor model, given
below, is a one-factor model:
The return on a security ri is
given by:
Where F = the
factor
ai = the
expected return on the security i if the factor has a value of zero
bi = the
sensitivity of security i to this factor
εi = the random
error term.
The returns on
security i are related to two main components. The first of these involves the
factor F. Factor F affects all security returns but with different
sensitivities. The sensitivity of security i is return to F is bi. Securities
that have small values for this parameter will react only slightly as F
changes, whereas when bi is large, variations in F cause large movements in the
return on security i.
As a concrete
example, think of F as the return on a market index (e.g. the Sensex or the
Nifty), the variations in which cause variations in individual security
returns. Hence, this term causes movements in individual security returns that
are related. If two securities have positive sensitivities to the factor, both
will tend to move in the same direction.
The second term
in the factor model is a random error term, which is assumed to be uncorrelated
across different stocks. We denote this term εi and call it the idiosyncratic
return component for stock i. An important property of the idiosyncratic
component is that it is assumed to be uncorrelated with F, the common factor in
stock returns. The expected value of random error term is zero.
According to one
factor model, the expected return on security i, can be written as:
Where denotes
the expected value of the factor. The random error term drops out as the
expected value of the random error term is zero. F
This equation
can be used to estimate the expected return on the security. For example, if
the factor F is the GDP growth rate, and the expected GDP growth rate is 5%, ai
= 4% and bi = 2, then the expected return is equal to 4% + 2 x 5% = 14%.
The variance of
any security in the single factor model is equal to:
Where F2 = the
variance of the factor F
εi 2 = the
variance of the random error term εi.
Thus if the
variance of the factor F2 = 0.0003
Variance of the
random error term εi 2 = 0.0015
bi = 2
Variance of the
security = 22 x 0.0003 + 0.0015 = 0.0027
Standard
deviation of the security = √variance =√0.0027 = 0.0520 = 5.2 %.
In a single
factor model, the covariance between any two securities i and j is equal to:
Where bi and bj
= the factor sensitivities of the two securities SDsF2 = the variance of the
factor F
Arbitrage
Pricing Theory (APT)
Modern portfolio theory helps an investor to
identify his optimal portfolio from umpteen number of security portfolios that
can be constructed. We have seen in earlier units how the risk-return framework
(using expected return and standard deviation of return of securities) along
with all the covariances between the securities’ return is used to derive the
curved efficient set of Markowitz. For a given risk-free rate, the investor
identifies the tangency portfolio and determines the linear efficient set
(Capital Market Line). The investor invests in the tangency portfolio and
either borrows or lends at the risk-free rate, the amount of borrowing or lending
depends on his risk-return preferences.
With a large numbers of
securities, the number of statistical inputs required for using the Markowitz
model is tremendous. The correlation or covariance between every pair of
securities must be evaluated in order to estimate portfolio risk.
The task of identifying the
curved Markowitz efficient set can be greatly simplified by introducing a return-generating
process. Return generating process is a statistical method that explains how the return
on a security is generated. we have studied one type of return-generating
model, i.e. the market model. This is a single-factor model which relates a
security’s return to a single factor, which is the return on a market index.
However, the
return on a security may depend on more than a single factor, necessitating the
use of multiple factor models. Multiple factor models relate the return on a
security to different factors in the economy, like the expected inflation, GDP
growth rate, interest rate, tax rate changes etc.
Factor models or
index models assume that the return on a security is sensitive to the movement
of multiple factors. To the extent that returns are indeed affected by a
variety of factors, the multiple factor models are seen to be more useful than
the market model.
Arbitrage
Pricing Theory (APT) is a factor model that was developed by Stephen Ross. It
starts with the assumption that security returns are related to an unknown
number of unknown factors. It does not specify what these factors are. Unlike
CAPM, APT does not rely on measuring the performance of the market. Instead, it
directly relates the price of the security to fundamental factors. What these
factors are is not indicated by the theory, and needs to be empirically
determined.
Capital Asset Pricing Model
(CAPM), and Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) are two of the most commonly used
models for pricing risky assets based on their relevant risks.
CAPM calculates the required rate
of return for any risky asset based on the security’s beta. Beta is a measure
of the movement of the security’s return with the return on the market
portfolio, which includes all available securities and where the proportion of
each security in the portfolio is its market value as a percentage of total
market value of all securities.
The problem with CAPM is that
such a market portfolio is hypothetical and not observable and we have to use a
market index like the S&P 500 or Sensex as a proxy for the market
portfolio.
However, indexes are imperfect
proxies for overall market as no single index includes all capital assets,
including stocks, bonds, real estate, collectibles, etc. Besides, the indexes
do not fully capture the relevant risk factors in the economy.
An alternative pricing theory
with fewer assumptions, the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT), has been developed
by Stephen Ross. It can calculate expected return without taking recourse to
the market portfolio. It is a multi-factor model for determining the required
rate of return which means that it takes into account economy factors as well.
APT calculates relations among expected returns that will rule out arbitrage by
investors.
APT requires three assumptions:
1) Returns can be
described by a factor model.
2) There are no
arbitrage opportunities.
3) There are large numbers of
securities that permit the formation of portfolios that diversify the
firm-specific risk of individual stocks.
APT starts with the assumption
that security returns are related to an unknown number of unknown factors.
These factors can be GDP (Gross domestic product), market interest rate, the
rate of inflation, or any random variable that impacts security prices. For
simplicity, let us assume that there is only one factor (such as the GDP growth
rate) that impacts the security price. In this one-factor APT model, the
security return is:
Where F1 = Factor
ai = Expected return on the
security i if the factor has a value of zero
bi = Sensitivity of security i to
this factor (also known as factor loading for security i)
ε I = Random error term.
Imagine an
investor holds 3 stocks and the market value of stock 1 is $250,000, of stock 2
is $250,000 and of stock 3 is $1,000,000. Thus the investor’s wealth is equal
to $1,500,000. These three stocks have the following returns and sensitivities.
Do these expected returns and
factor sensitivities represent an equilibrium condition? If not, what happens
to restore equilibrium?
Principle of Arbitrage or Arbitrage Theory
APT shows that for
well-diversified portfolios, if the portfolio’s expected return (price) is not
equal to the expected return predicted by the portfolio’s sensitivities (bi),
then there will be an arbitrage opportunity. According to APT, an investor will
explore the possibility of forming an arbitrage portfolio to increase the
expected return on his current portfolio without increasing risk. An arbitrage
opportunity arises if an investor can construct a zero investment portfolio
with no risk, but with a positive profit. Since no investment is required, an
investor can create large positions to secure large levels of profits.
An arbitrage portfolio does not
require any additional commitment of funds. Let Xi represent the change in the
investor’s holding of security i (as a proportion of total wealth. It is
therefore, the proportion of security i in the arbitrage portfolio). Thus the
requirement of no new investment can be expressed as:
X1 + X2 + X3 =0
An arbitrage portfolio has no
sensitivity to any factor. Sensitivity of a portfolio is the weighted average
of the sensitivities of the securities in the portfolio to that factor, this
requirement can be expressed as b1X1 + b2X2 + b3X3 =0
In the current example,
1.0 X1 + 2.5 X2 + 2.0 X3 =0
At this point we have two
equations and three unknowns. As there are more unknowns than equations, an
infinite number of combinations of X1, X2 and X3 will satisfy the requirements.
As a way of finding one such arbitrage portfolio, arbitrarily assign a value of
0.2 to X1. Thus we have 2 equations and 2 unknowns.
0.2 + X2 + X3 =0
0.2 + 2.5 X2 + 2.0 X3 =0
Solving these two equations gives
a value of X2 = 0.4 and X3 = -0.6
Hence, a possible arbitrage
portfolio is one with X1= 0.2, X2= 0.4 and X3 = -0.6.
The expected return of an
arbitrage portfolio must be greater than 0. Thus to see whether an arbitrage
portfolio has actually been identified, its expected return must be determined.
If it is positive an arbitrage portfolio has been identified.
Thus the last requirement is:
X1 r1 + X2 r2 + X3 r3 > 0
Or 10% X1 + 18% X2 + 12% X3
Substituting the values:
= 10% x 0.2 + 18% x 0.4 + 12% x
(-0.6) = 2%. Since this is positive, an arbitrage portfolio has been
identified.
The arbitrage portfolio involves
buying 0.2 x $1,500,000 = $300,000 of stock 1, 0.4 x $1,500,000 = $600,000 of
stock 2 and selling 0.6 x $1,500,000 = $900,000 of stock 3.
Return on old portfolio
Return on new portfolio
Weights of new portfolio
Stock 1: 0.1667 + 0.2 = 0.3367
Stock 2: 0.1667 + 0.4 = 0.5667
Stock 3: 0.6666 – 0.6 = 0.0666
Thus, we see that the new
portfolio gives a return which is 14.67% - 12.67% = 2 % more than the old
portfolio as the calculations above have indicated.
Sensitivity of old portfolio: 0.1667 x 1.0 + 0.1667 x 2.5 +
0.6666 x 2.0 = 1.916
Sensitivity of new portfolio: 0.3667 x 1.0 + 0.5667 x 2.5 +
0.0666 x 2.0 = 1.916
Thus, the sensitivity of the old
portfolio is the same as that of the new one. The risk would also be
approximately the same as the difference in the risk is only due to non-factor
risk.
What is the effect of buying
stocks 1 and 2 and selling stock 3? As everyone would be doing it to exploit
the arbitrage opportunity, the prices of stocks 1 and 2 will rise because of
the buying pressure and the price of stock 3 will fall due to the selling
pressure. Consequently, the return on stocks 1 and 2 will fall and the return
on stock 3 will increase. This buying and selling will continue till all
arbitrage possibilities are significantly reduced or eliminated. At this point,
there exists a linear relationship between expected returns and sensitivities:
This equation is the asset
pricing equation of the APT when returns are generated by a single factor. As
an illustration, suppose, 0 = 5 and 1= 4 for the example above,
Thus, the expected returns of
stocks 1 and 2 have fallen from 10% and 18% to 9% and 15% respectively, due to
buying pressure and the expected return of stock 3 has increased from 12% to
13% because of selling pressure.
Thus, in equilibrium, the
expected return on any security is a linear function of the security’s
sensitivity to the factor, bi.
is the return on an asset that has no
sensitivity to the factor (bi =0). Hence, it is the risk free rate (rf). Thus,
we can write the equation for expected return as:
Identifying the Factors in the
APT
APT does not identify the factors
to be used in the theory. Therefore, they need to be empirically determined. In
practice, and in theory, one stock might be more sensitive to one factor than
another. For example, the price of ONGC shares will be sensitive to the price
of crude oil, but not Colgate shares. In fact, APT leaves it up to the investor
or the analyst to identify each of the factors for a particular stock. So the
real challenge for the investor is to identify three things:
the factors affecting a particular stock
the expected returns for each of these factors
the
sensitivity of the stock to each of these factors.
Identifying and
quantifying each of these factors is no trivial matter and is one of the
reasons why CAPM remains the dominant theory to describe the relationship
between a stock's risk and return.
Ross and others
have identified the following macro-economic factors as significant in
explaining the return on a stock:
growth rate in industrial production
rate of inflation
spread between long-term and short-term interest rates
spread between low grade and high grade bonds
growth rate in GNP (Gross national product)
growth in aggregate sales in the economy
rate of return on S&P 500
investor confidence
shifts in the
yield curve.
With that as
guidance, the rest of the work is left to the stock analyst to identify
specific factors for a particular stock.
Arbitrage
Pricing Theory vs. the Capital Asset Pricing Model
APT and CAPM are
the two most influential theories on stock and asset pricing today. The APT
model is different from the CAPM in case of less restrictiveness in its
assumptions. APT allows the individual investor to develop their model that
explains the expected return for a particular asset.
Intuitively, the
APT hold true because it removes the CAPM restrictions and basically states
that the expected return on an asset is a function of many factors and the
sensitivity of stock to these factors. As these factors change, so does the
expected return on the stock, and therefore its value to the investor. However,
the potentially large number of factors means that more factor sensitivities
have to be calculated. There is also no guarantee that all the relevant factors
have been identified. This added complexity is the reason APT is less widely
used than CAPM.
In the CAPM
theory, the expected return on a stock can be described by the movement of that
stock relative to the rest of the stock market. The CAPM theory is a simplified
version of the APT, where the only factor considered is the risk of a
particular stock relative to the rest of the stock market–as described by the
stock's beta.
From a practical
standpoint, CAPM remains the dominant pricing model used today. When compared
to the APT, CAPM is more refined and relatively simpler to calculate.
Factor
Models
Single Factor Model and Variance
The simplest factor model, given
below, is a one-factor model:
The return on a security ri is
given by:
Where F = the
factor
ai = the
expected return on the security i if the factor has a value of zero
bi = the
sensitivity of security i to this factor
εi = the random
error term.
The returns on
security i are related to two main components. The first of these involves the
factor F. Factor F affects all security returns but with different
sensitivities. The sensitivity of security i is return to F is bi. Securities
that have small values for this parameter will react only slightly as F
changes, whereas when bi is large, variations in F cause large movements in the
return on security i.
As a concrete
example, think of F as the return on a market index (e.g. the Sensex or the
Nifty), the variations in which cause variations in individual security
returns. Hence, this term causes movements in individual security returns that
are related. If two securities have positive sensitivities to the factor, both
will tend to move in the same direction.
The second term
in the factor model is a random error term, which is assumed to be uncorrelated
across different stocks. We denote this term εi and call it the idiosyncratic
return component for stock i. An important property of the idiosyncratic
component is that it is assumed to be uncorrelated with F, the common factor in
stock returns. The expected value of random error term is zero.
According to one
factor model, the expected return on security i, can be written as:
Where denotes
the expected value of the factor. The random error term drops out as the
expected value of the random error term is zero. F
This equation
can be used to estimate the expected return on the security. For example, if
the factor F is the GDP growth rate, and the expected GDP growth rate is 5%, ai
= 4% and bi = 2, then the expected return is equal to 4% + 2 x 5% = 14%. The variance
of any security in the single factor model is equal to:
Two-factor Models and Variance
Comments
Post a Comment